sexta-feira, 19 de junho de 2009

Par délicatesse

"Chanson de la plus haute tour
Oisive jeunesse
A tout asservie,
Par délicatesseJ'ai perdu ma vie.
Ah ! Que le temps vienne
Où les cœurs s'éprennent.
Je me suis dit : laisse,
Et qu'on ne te voie :
Et sans la promesse
De plus hautes joies.
Que rien ne t'arrête,
Auguste retraite.
J'ai tant fait patience
Qu'à jamais j'oublie;
,Craintes et souffrances
Aux cieux sont parties.
Et la soif malsaine
Obscurcit mes veines.
Ainsi la prairie
A l'oubli livrée,
Grandie, et fleurie
D'encens et d'ivraies
Au bourdon farouche
De cent sales mouches.
Ah ! Mille veuvages
De la si pauvre âme
Qui n'a que l'image
De la Notre-Dame !
Est-ce que l'on prie
La Vierge Marie ?
Oisive jeunesse
A tout asservie,
Par délicatesse
J'ai perdu ma vie.
Ah ! Que le temps vienne
Où les coeurs s'éprennent !"

A. Rimbaud.

quinta-feira, 11 de junho de 2009

Deu no Economist on line



The Amazon The future of the forest
Jun 11th 2009 MANAUS From The Economist print editionBrazil’s government hopes that land reform in the Amazon will slow deforestation. Greens doubt it
Still Pictures
THE tiny village, where naked Ticuna Indians live in wooden houses raised on stilts, looks out over one of the rivers that becomes the Amazon. No place seems farther removed from the ups and downs of the world economy. But this is misleading. The Ticuna, who now have a large reservation at Novo Paraíso near Brazil’s borders with Colombia and Peru, took their first steps towards globalisation when they had the misfortune to encounter Portuguese raiders several centuries ago. Later, rubber drew the Amazon into the list of hinterlands that could be tapped if supplies were tight elsewhere, allowing growth to accelerate in much of the world from the 19th century onwards. And today new demands on the Amazon’s riches will determine the future of the forest.About 900 miles (1,500km) downriver to the east, in Amazonas state, stands Manaus. Rubber barons built the city from the 1860s onwards. Its early residents made up for their distance from the European centres of fashion by trying to outdo Paris during the belle époque in drinking and debauchery. Now Manaus’s Zona Franca is the workshop for most of the televisions, washing machines and other white goods sold in Brazil. Special arrangements allow firms such as Sony and LG to import parts tax-free from elsewhere in the world and assemble them there. Despite being surrounded on all sides by thick forest, Manaus hums with manufacturing.Some 350 miles to the south-east, in Pará state, the high gold price has encouraged a few hundred garimpeiros, or wildcat miners, to follow rumours of a strike and trek for days through the forest to a place, not far from Itaituba, which they have optimistically named “Bom Jesus”. They live in shacks with tarpaulins to keep off the rain, digging square holes and sifting through the red soil in the hope of finding a seam of gold. Malaria lurks there, and the men say there is cyanide in the water. Apart from a visiting government minister and some other dignitaries and journalists who have come for the day by helicopter, there is nothing to indicate that the Brazilian state exists. Its place has been taken by a local boss who claims to own the land (though it actually belongs to the federal government) and takes a percentage of any gold found, while charging the workers exorbitant prices for supplies that are dropped off by small planes.South by 400 miles, in Mato Grosso state, the Amazon meets the agricultural frontier. Much of the world’s growing demand for protein is satisfied here. The state, which was once thought to have poor farmland, has been transformed over the past few decades and is now the country’s biggest producer of soyabeans for vegetable oils and cattle-feed. Mato Grosso is also home to an unproductive kind of agriculture, which involves ranching small numbers of cattle on newly deforested land. The forest in the state shrank by 105 square miles in the three months from November to January, according to the Brazilian Space Research Institute, which uses satellites to monitor deforestation.All these places are part of the Amazon rainforest, an area one-and-a-half times the size of India, or nearly eight times the size of Texas. Most of it lies within Brazil. It is home to 20m Brazilians, or 10% of the country’s population. Many of them live a hardscrabble existence in places that are hot, wet, often disease-ridden and sometimes dangerous. These people have gone from being heroes who answered the government’s call to populate and subdue an empty region, to environmental criminals who are wrecking the planet, all the while standing on the same spot and doing what they have done for decades.No government would think of condemning so many voters to persistent poverty in the name of saving trees. Moving them is impractical and would be unjust, since the state moved them in the first place, under a policy that began in the 1960s and lasted for 20 years. (Other institutions helped too; the World Bank provided a loan that financed a large migration from the south of the country to Rondônia state in the days before it cared about greenery.) A vast migration was accomplished with promises of free land, subsidies and a slightly menacing marketing campaign that exhorted people to ocupar para não entregar (“occupy it or lose it”). Parts of Brazil’s government still fret that covetous foreign powers may try to annexe the Amazon forest unless the country can find something useful to do with it.President Luiz Inácio Lula da Silva’s government has often seemed to sympathise more with these voters than with environmentalists, who are anyway politically weak in Brazil. His first environment minister, Marina Silva, resigned in frustration last year. This pleased the bancada ruralista, an informal block of representatives who defend agricultural interests. They were glad to see the back of Ms Silva, the daughter of rubber-tappers who grew up in the forest and became the most eloquent spokesman for the need to preserve it. This agricultural lobby makes up 20-25% of Congress, according to João Augusto de Castro Neves, a political consultant.
Fires, grass, cattleTo improve the lives of Brazilians living in the Amazon, the government has devised a set of policies known as Plano Amazônia. They envisage an expansion of road-building in the forest, as well as some big hydroelectric projects. Both are loathed by people who want to preserve the trees. Plano Amazônia also contains measures to slow deforestation, but these will be hard to enforce. Money is short, the area to be policed is vast, and the folk who make money when the trees are cut down are endlessly ingenious.
Many people derive their income from deforestation. In Tailândia, a town in Pará surrounded by sawmills, some 70% of the population depends on logging in some way, according to local officials in the state’s finance ministry. The loggers work in tandem with cattle farmers: once the loggers take the best trees from an area, the rest is cleared and burnt. The farmers then sow grass and raise cattle. The land is quickly exhausted as pasture, but it then passes to another type of farming, while the loggers and cattle move farther into the forest and begin all over again. This pattern helps to explain why the rate of deforestation tends to move with prices for beef and soya, with a lag of about a year. Yet it is a wasteful way of using land. A recent study of some 300 municipalities in the Brazilian Amazon, published in the latest edition of Science, shows that deforested areas enjoy a short economic boom, then quickly fall back to previous levels of development and productivity as the frontier moves on. Deforestation also, of course, reduces the rainfall on which Brazil’s agriculture depends.Consumers in America and western Europe who mind about deforestation may think they have some influence over all this. A recent study by Greenpeace encouraged them, by trying to show that bits of Amazonian cow were finding their way on to supermarket shelves in the rich world. They are wrong, however. The five leading markets for Brazil’s enormous beef exports (the country ships more of it than the total of the three next-largest exporters, Australia, Argentina and Uruguay) are Russia, Iran, China, Venezuela and Egypt, according to Roberto Giannetti da Fonseca of the Association of Brazilian Meat Exporters. And in any case the beef produced in the Amazon is mostly eaten by Brazilians in neighbouring states.Even so, Mr da Fonseca says his association would like to see cattle-ranching removed from the Amazon, because of the damage it does to the reputation of exporters. The big soyabean exporters have already pledged not to buy from growers in the Amazon. Greenpeace, which helped to design the agreement, counts it as a success. This just leaves an internal market for cheap soyabeans and beef, which supports 30m head of cattle in the Amazon out of a total of 200m in the country.Given the hardships that farmers in the Amazon face, it may seem surprising that they do not just give up. One reason is that clearance and cattle bring in extra money from other sources. The farmers are also property developers of a kind. Jungle land can be grabbed for nothing, avoiding what is normally a huge outlay in farming. And ranchers often sell the land they have deforested to another user, even though they do not legally own it. Most people who study deforestation reckon this creates an incentive for farmers to push farther into the forest, rather than staying where they are, spending money on improving their land and raising productivity.Ending this cycle is one aim of a land-reform bill that was recently approved in Congress, though not without controversy. This law is now with the president, who has the power to veto some of it. The government claims that the legislation will at last enable it to discover which farmers are operating on illegal land and in the informal economy, and in the future will make it possible to work out who is committing environmental crimes. Many environmentalists, however, think the law merely rewards criminal behaviour. Ms Silva has appealed to Lula to use his veto.
Get off my landHoldings in America’s Great Plains, impressively neat and rectilinear from the air, were laid out in various early land laws and then parcelled out among pioneers. Brazil’s frontier has never benefited from such an elegant application of geometry. A study from Imazon, a non-profit research outfit, suggests that just 14% of privately owned land in the Amazon is backed by a secure title deed. The rest is covered by fake documents (usually lovingly antiqued) or simply by right of settlement.In the most contested parts of the forest, in Pará state, conflicts over who owns what are sometimes settled with a gun. In 2005 the murder of Dorothy Mae Stang, an American nun and environmental campaigner who lived in Pará, brought this to the attention of a wider public. In his trial, the man who pulled the trigger said he had been paid 50 reais ($20) for the job.
Eyevine
Tranquillity on the riverThere are still gunmen for hire in Pará, according to the police in Tailândia, a town of 25,000 people. Rosenildo Modesta Lima, the local police commander, says that when he arrived there a couple of years ago there were seven murders over one weekend; now there are two or three a week. The police are on edge. Just the other day a heavily armed gang attacked a police station in a neighbouring town in an attempt to get more weapons. Two gang members were killed and a third injured.The new law will interpose the Brazilian state into this mess, judging between competing claims, handing smaller plots of land to their apparent owners and reclaiming very large ones (in excess of 1,500 hectares or 3,700 acres) for the state. This will undoubtedly entrench some old injustices. “It’s very hard to know who killed someone 20 years ago to get a piece of land and who just arrived recently,” says Denis Minev, the planning secretary for Amazonas state (which has a good record on deforestation). Even so, in the long run the measure may prove useful. “Land regularisation is of fundamental importance for halting deforestation,” says Carlos Minc, Brazil’s environment minister.Enforcing the new regime will be as difficult as ever. IBAMA, the federal agency charged with this task, collects less than 1% of the fines it imposes during operations in the Amazon. “This is not something that is feared as a serious threat by people who break the law,” says Roberto Smeraldi of Amigos da Terra, an NGO. The sporadic weakness of the Brazilian state is partly to blame for this. But any government would struggle to police the frontier between forest and farmland, which is far longer than America’s border with Mexico.This is why many environmentalists now argue that the only way to fix the problem is to give people who live at the frontier something more profitable to do. The government has begun to change the region’s economies. Since July last year farmers without titles to their land are supposed to be denied access to subsidised credit, though this too is hard to enforce.Efforts to commercialise forest products, from Amazon river fish to oils for use in cosmetics, are also under way. Amigos da Terra, in a study of these businesses, finds them to be profitable when they form clusters and turn out finished products. “I am convinced that in 20 years we will have a viable forest economy,” says Mr Smeraldi. “Only by then we will have lost a lot of forest.”Speeding up this process is one of the motives behind the $1 billion donation for the Amazon announced in September by Norway’s government. The Brazilian government has set up an Amazon Fund for this money and any future donations. Norway will have no say in how it is used, but the amount of money it releases from the fund will be linked to Brazil’s success in slowing deforestation. Germany will give something to the fund too. Turid Rodrigues Eusébio, Norway’s ambassador to Brasília, says lots of other countries are watching Norway to see how the experiment goes, and will chip in if it is a success.
Google Earth
Depredation from spaceAmazon states hope to acquire another stream of money, in the form of payments for not cutting down trees, from the UN initiative known as REDD, which will be discussed in Copenhagen in December (see article). Payments of this kind are already being made in Amazonas state: $8.1m from private companies such as Marriott hotels and Bradesco, a big bank, is being handed over by the state government to 6,000 families in exchange for not cutting down any more trees. The challenge is to extend such schemes to the trees on the edge of the farmland, which are most at risk. Still, argues Ms Rodrigues Eusébio, it will take more than changing cattle-ranchers into nut-gatherers to put a stop to deforestation. To bring a more elevated form of economic development to the region, Brazil’s government is convinced that it needs to build more roads in the forest. This too is controversial. Some 80% of deforestation happens within 30 miles of a road. Seen from Google Earth, the southern part of Pará state looks as if someone has dropped large fish skeletons on the jungle, as spines of deforestation push into the trees from either side of the roads. Deforestation is more severe where a road is good, which is why the proposed asphalting of the BR-163, from Cuiabá in Mato Grosso to Santarém in Pará, is held up by a legal wrangle.However unpalatable road-building is, it may be needed if the people who live in the Amazon are to lead a better life. “The Everglades are very beautiful, but America did rule out building roads through them to connect Miami with other parts of Florida,” says Mr Minev of Amazonas state. The government now knows how to build roads without unleashing the loggers, he argues. Amazonas has recently signed an agreement creating nature reserves on either side of the BR-319, which runs from Manaus to Porto Velho. The road will help to integrate Manaus into the rest of the country’s economy. When the Zona Franca was established in 1967, it took 15-20 days to get goods to consumers in São Paulo, in the country’s south-east. It takes the same amount of time today. In this vision of the Amazon, the forest will be preserved as a large national park with sprinklings of industry added to enrich its inhabitants. The agriculture at its edge will be more productive than it is today, making use of abandoned land and raising yields to meet domestic and foreign demand without encroaching farther into the jungle. This is aim is plausible, as well as commendable, but it will take decades to accomplish. In the meantime, the forest will continue to shrink. The fight today is over how fast that happens.

quinta-feira, 23 de abril de 2009

Texto de referência sobre mercado e mudança climática

Pollution, Prices, and Perception
by Daniel Gabaldon
Carbon regulation will be unexpectedly complex — and business leaders will need to plan their approach accordingly.
http://www.strategy-business.com/press/article/09101?pg=all&tid=230

Climate change is unlike any other environmental or public-health challenge that industrialized democracies have ever faced. The problem’s sheer scale over time and space, its protean and complex causes, the massive cost of addressing it (and the even more massive cost of ignoring it) all defy our intuition. And this immense complexity will confront executives as they begin to contemplate what the realities of climate policy will mean for their businesses.
Much of the current discussion among business and policy leaders involves details of how to apply a market-based “cap and trade” system. This is, of course, the scheme in which regulators prescribe emissions limits (the “caps”) and set up a system of fungible credits that allow businesses to comply with those limits (the “trade”) — thus creating an incentive to find the lowest-cost, most efficient ways to reduce emissions. It is clear that most governments will end up relying primarily, or even exclusively, on this sort of market-focused approach, and that it will provide a national and global context for business action on climate change.
But cap and trade by itself will be insufficient, for two reasons. First, given current technologies, the price of CO2 credits would need to rise to politically unsustainable levels to achieve the emissions re­ductions that most scientists think are necessary to avoid irreversible damage to the environment. Second, many of the most powerful measures for reducing emissions involve new infrastructure, new technical standards, regional planning, and basic research — domains in which prices and markets, by themselves, are inadequate.
The nature of climate change, as well as the realities of economic and political behavior, make it more likely that a multipronged regulatory approach will end up being used — incorporating, but not limited to, market-based approaches. Although it is impossible to predict exactly what form this set of private and public policies will eventually take, the most realistic possibilities are coming into focus today. Unfortunately, some companies, in planning for a post-carbon future, are betting on strategies that would pay out only in more extreme (and unlikely) scenarios. Currently available carbon sequestration technol­ogy, for instance, makes sense only when the prices of CO2 credits are extremely high; building conventional coal-powered generation plants would work financially only if no limits were placed on CO2. A clear-eyed assessment of the strengths and limits of a cap and trade system suggests a more nu­anced strategic path for energy and industrial producers.
Costs and ComplexitiesClimate change is an inherently challenging issue to come to terms with. First is the sheer magnitude of the problem. Under “business as usual” scenarios in which carbon emissions continue growing (or even level off), the total cost of climate change–related damage over the next two centuries is estimated to be “equivalent to an average re­duction in global per-capita consumption of at least 5 percent, now and forever” — and 20 percent in the most vulnerable countries. (The source of these estimates is Nicholas Stern’s authoritative 2007 report, The Economics of Climate Change, published by Cambridge University Press.) These costs can be mitigated, but only if power-sector emissions are cut by 60 to 75 percent, and extensive cuts are made in transportation emissions as well. Even the best-designed approaches may require trillions of dollars to implement. For most of us, these figures are so enormous as to be practically meaningless.
The problem of how to address climate change is equally perplexing, in part because of the diffuse chain of causality and extensive time delays involved. Emissions entering the atmosphere today might have negligible impacts in the short run, but could contribute directly to dangerous greenhouse gas (GHG) levels 100 years or more in the future. The best technological fixes are not yet commercially available, and thus we don’t know how much they will cost to deploy. And the sheer variety of human activities that result in emissions poses its own challenges. Acid rain was reduced successfully by cap and trade, but it was primarily caused by sulfur dioxide and nitrous oxide emissions, both largely from coal-fired power plants; GHG emissions originate from a wide variety of activities and sectors of the economy. No single source of atmospheric carbon represents more than 30 or 40 percent of the total. Indeed, the only current consensus about solutions appears to be that no silver bullet exists.
And of course, the entire discussion is occurring at a time of imperfect and rapidly evolving science as well as highly partisan perspectives. Issues of equity — such as whether rich or poor nations should bear the costs or whether today’s uncertainties justify the costs that future generations might bear — abound. Efforts to establish appropriate interest rates for cost-benefit analysis of alternative policies end up tangled in what appear to be irreconcilable contradictions.
Despite this issue’s many com­plexities, public support for action on climate change is wide and growing. Many nations have already adopted mandatory limits on CO2 emissions; so have numerous states, cities, and companies in the industrialized world. The debate over the cap and trade system in particular is moving beyond the question, Should we do it? to the multiple questions of how to design it. And here again there are disagreements: over the percentage of the emissions rights that should be given free to companies versus auctioned off; over the pace and sever­ity of emissions reductions; and over the ap­propriate use of the proceeds by governments. In general, these de­bates come down to a question of distribution: whether to set up the details of allocation to favor particular geographies (areas depen­dent on coal-fired generation versus those amenable to windmills), in­dustries (energy-intensive manufacturers ver­sus service sectors), or types of firms (electric power companies with large nuclear and re­newable portfolios versus those with mostly coal-fired units).
However, the heated quality of these debates can obscure a more fundamental issue related to the nature of markets themselves.
Emissions Market OmissionsWinston Churchill famously said that democracy was the worst political system, except for all the others. Something similar could be said about using cap and trade markets to reduce greenhouse gases. Markets may be imperfect and in­complete, but all the alternatives (at least in­dividually) are worse. Classic command-and-control regulation would be massively inefficient and probably politically unpalatable. Carbon taxes are widely viewed as a political nonstarter, at least in the United States. And doing nothing, at either the corporate or the national level, is too risky a proposition.
As previously noted, cap and trade regimes were applied with great success in the regulation of acid rain, beginning in 1989. (See “The Making of a Market-Minded Environmentalist,” by Fred Krupp, s+b, Summer 2008.) Existing regulatory regimes in Europe, the U.S. Northeast, and California are using similar approaches. The benefits of these market-based regimes, compared with quantitative or technological mandates, are well known. Markets create price signals that allow billions of uncoordinated choices to be directed to reduce carbon, while inducing technological and business innovation, without the need for centralized control.
But the shortcomings of markets in reducing emissions cannot be ignored. First and foremost, as a recent Booz & Company survey of U.S. consumers showed, many people are unprepared for the energy prices they would have to pay under a cap and trade regime. It’s no surprise that in the U.S. Midwest and South, where electricity rates have remained steady or fallen in real terms for two decades and where political support for addressing climate change is low, people balk at the idea of steeply increased rates. But environmentally and socially progressive survey respondents in places like the Northeast and Pacific Northwest were also disinclined to pay higher prices for electricity or transportation fuel, even when told it would reflect the need to reduce carbon emissions. Instead, the research showed that consumers across the United States and of all political persuasions believe someone else — typically big business — should shoulder the costs. This suggests that attempts to foist price increases on consumers to reduce climate change would be politically unsustainable, perhaps depleting the widespread goodwill that is currently bestowed on action against climate change.
Unfortunately, energy prices under most proposed cap and trade systems still wouldn’t be high enough to move consumers to take the steps needed to mitigate climate change. And evidence suggests that, no matter how high energy prices might get, they would still be insufficient motivators in themselves. For example, many people still don’t take advantage of home insulation, weatherization (modifying buildings to make them less vulnerable to heat, cold, and moisture), and other opportunities to improve energy efficiency, despite such solutions being economically attractive at current prices. Habit, ignorance, and inconvenience serve as durable barriers to behavior change, regardless of the incentives.
Another shortcoming of cap and trade systems is their reliance on pecuniary incentives — which have a poor track record at influencing certain types of human behavior. Consider the millions of people who choose to donate blood, to volunteer for military service during wartime, to donate time to local community efforts, and to voluntarily sort recyclables from trash every week. Feeling good about oneself or receiving social approbation or blame can work where markets don’t — or where they are viewed as socially inappropriate. The same appears to be true in the case of popular attitudes about climate change. About 80 percent of respondents in the Booz & Company survey said that they would pay a substantial premium for their own renewable solution, but they would not pay even a small percentage of that amount in higher energy prices. For example, most respondents indicated that they would rather in­stall a solar panel on their home than pay even a small increase in their utility bill to reflect the cost of carbon reduction.
Finally, as the turmoil in the financial sector in the last half of 2008 reminded us, free markets don’t always direct people to the op­timal or most appropriate choices. In energy markets in general, the ability of prices to provide useful information is compromised by the lengthy time lags and giant scale of investments typical in this highly capital-intensive industry.
Recent wargame-style simulations conducted by Booz & Company on potential implications of climate regulations for the U.S. electric power sector — with executives from leading utilities and oil and gas companies as the participants — underscored this issue. As in the real world, even experienced players failed to anticipate the consequences of one another’s choices. The result was follow-the-herd waves of underinvestment and then overinvestment in new power generation, with emissions pricing rising to very high levels before crashing to near zero. In the real world, the European Union’s nascent emissions trading scheme has experienced similar volatility. This pattern could easily reappear in a U.S. cap and trade market.
Belts and SuspendersIn the end, the multifaceted nature of climate change, and the requisite shifts in behavior and investment needed to address it, renders problematic any approach that depends solely on a cap and trade program. What then will policymakers do? Rather than placing an undue burden on fragile market institutions, they will supplement the cap and trade system with several other venerable policy instruments.
Several climate change initiatives are already following this kind of diversified, belts-and-suspenders approach. For example, the California Global Warming Solutions Act of 2006 established a landmark climate change abatement program that blends regulatory and market mechanisms with the goal of reducing GHG emissions to only 20 percent of 1990 levels by 2050. Since transportation contributes 39 percent of California’s gross GHG emissions, targeting that sector was a key element. California employs a custom mix of policies, including vehicle efficiency and mileage standards, mandates for lower levels of carbon in transportation fuels, and a transition from gasoline and diesel to alternative and renewable fuels. In addition, the state awards US$120 million annually in grants, revolving loans, loan guarantees, and other measures to develop and deploy innovative fuel and vehicle technologies. California also aims to increase electricity production from renewable resources to 33 percent by 2020, through a combination of standards for buildings and ap­pliances, and programs delivered by utility companies, local governments, community organizations, and the private sector. Climate Action Team subgroups have been formed in sectors such as agriculture, forestry, and energy to identify and analyze measures for reducing emissions. Land use and agricultural policies are also included in this robust portfolio.
Across the Atlantic, the German government has implemented a similar plan for a 40 percent re­duction in the country’s GHG emissions by 2020. The plan, which targets sectors such as agriculture and transportation, also calls for boosting Germany’s share of electricity produced from renewable en­ergy to 25 to 30 percent by 2020. (Germany already has the highest share of installed wind energy ca­pacity in the world.) In addition, the government is implementing a package of emissions reduction policies, as well as 14 new laws and regulations designed to encourage businesses to conserve energy. And by providing hundreds of millions of euros in subsidies to encourage home and building owners to install efficient heating systems, the German government hopes to increase the energy efficiency of buildings. Australia’s plans also take a multi-instrument approach.
Given the novelty, complexity, and scale of the challenge, governments will undoubtedly experiment with a variety of approaches. However, over time they will gravitate toward policies that reflect the underlying realities of emissions reduction, national and local politics, and economics. That almost certainly means, in the end, that the regulatory landscape will reflect these three broad principles:
1. Low-cost solutions. The cheapest sources, by far, of GHG emissions reductions are improved energy efficiency and land conservation and reforestation programs; that has been the experience of dozens of companies and governments around the world. In the past, “sexier” and higher-cost op­tions, such as photovoltaic solar or “clean coal” technologies, have often received greater attention and funding. That will change as cost-benefit trade-offs favor such measures as efficiency standards for buildings and electronics. Automation will also help by reducing the behavioral barriers to capturing more energy-efficiency savings. For example, advanced control technologies, com­bined with real-time price data and information exchanges enabled by smart grid systems, will allow devices to “decide” when to reduce load as a function of overall electricity grid conditions (which in turn incorporate carbon prices).
The lowest-cost option for reducing emissions will often vary by geography, and by the stage of local economic development. A 2008 study by the World Wildlife Fund and Booz & Company found that the most significant sources of emissions shift significantly over the lifetime of a city or region. During the early stages of economic development, the greatest reduction is possible from designing new transportation and communications infrastructures to support dense hab­itation and high bandwidth. (Internet connectivity can reduce commuting and other travel and enable much smarter energy use within buildings.) For more established cities with slower growth, the most effective sources of emissions reduction are changes in electricity supply and energy efficiency.
2. Streamlined markets. The design of carbon emissions markets is still evolving. One key trend, for example, is the movement to in­corporate “offsets” such as forests, which play a large role in reducing CO2 but are not always accepted as viable parts of a carbon trading program. Another likely development will be mechanisms to reduce price volatility. For example, some policymakers may apply to climate change some of the design principles that Harvard Professor William Hogan has proposed for taming wholesale electricity markets.
3. A long-term commitment. Until now, policymakers in many countries, including the U.S., have not provided the steady, long-term conditions needed for new technologies to flourish. At the heart of GHG reduction will be corporate choices about which multibillion-dollar, multiple-decade projects to fund. Unfortunately, companies seeking to invest in clean technology have faced an unpredictable, constantly shifting regulatory landscape. Subsidies stop and start. Laws change. Without a matching commitment from their political counterparts, business leaders can’t commit the capital over time that is needed to transform the sector.
Compare the fate of the U.S. wind power industry with that of the photovoltaic solar industry in Japan and Europe. In the U.S., investment in wind power has been dependent on a government- provided “production tax credit,” which has been offered and withdrawn in a series of stops and starts over the past several years. But the mechanism for subsidizing the photovoltaic solar industry in Japan, Germany, and elsewhere was ex­plicitly designed to be long-lived. The subsidies decreased in a slow and carefully planned fashion, thus creating incentives for producers to deliver reduced costs through increased scale, learning, and innovation. The resulting cost improvements and industry growth followed predictably. A similar comparison can be made with the nuclear industry. In the United States, shifting regulations contributed to spectacularly rising project costs, whereas in France, a more stable regulatory environment enabled rapid growth and lower project costs.
The most successful governments in a post-carbon world will be those that provide predictable long-term environments favoring investment and innovation. This will matter more than getting the market design or regulatory regime exactly right, or than picking winning technologies.
Making Better BetsIf public policies play out this way, then the path is clear for corporate decision makers in the energy and industrial sectors. Don’t bet on projects that pay out only with a very high CO2 price. For example, with current technologies, carbon sequestration is financially viable only if the price of CO2 remains above roughly $70 per ton. On the other hand, a status quo strategy that depends on carbon emissions remaining “free” — such as relying on traditionally coal-fired power generation — is also risky. The greatest opportunities for investment will be holistic urban or regional infrastructure makeovers, where the energy, transportation, water, and telecommunications systems are seen as interrelated and the financing, construction, technological development, and social design are all conceived in unison. (See “Lights! Water! Motion!” by Viren Doshi, Gary Schulman, and Daniel Gabaldon, s+b, Spring 2007.)
Many discussions of market-based solutions are either too optimistic or too pessimistic. They ignore and downplay the costs or they insist that the costs are too great for any action. The best corporate response involves a sober assessment of the strengths and limits of available options, in light of the complexity of the emerging regulatory, political, and social milieu. Envisioning a world in which so­ciety employs multiple tools to ad­dress climate change — including standards, research programs, subsidies, and interdiction, as well as carbon markets — opens up a much broader range of new opportunities than the narrow (though worthy) strategies currently being pursued. Clean coal, renewable generation, and the like are only the tip of the post-carbon iceberg. It is the actions under the surface — be­havior change, efficiencies, incremental in­novation, infrastructure design, and good management practice — that will ultimately have the greatest impact.

Reprint No. 09101
Author Profile:
Daniel Gabaldon is a principal with Booz & Company based in McLean, Va. He focuses on providing strategic advice to leading participants in the global energy and infrastructure sectors.

sábado, 18 de abril de 2009

Amianto e uso controlado (pelo STF)

Supremo mantém restrições a amianto
Luiza de Carvalho, de Brasília,

17/04/2009
Valor Econômico, Legislação & Tributos , pg E1


A indústria do amianto - fibra utilizada principalmente na fabricação de telhas e caixas d'água - não conseguiu derrubar no Supremo Tribunal Federal (STF) uma lei do município de São Paulo que proíbe o uso da substância. Ontem, em decisão monocrática, o ministro Ricardo Lewandowski negou uma liminar para suspender a Lei municipal nº 13.113, de 2001, em uma arguição de descumprimento de preceito fundamental (ADPF) ajuizada pela Confederação Nacional dos Trabalhadores na Indústria (CNTI). O STF deve decidir neste ano sobre o a permissão para uso do amianto no país.
A principal discussão sobre o tema está pendente de julgamento na corte, em uma ação direta de inconstitucionalidade (Adin) ajuizada pela Associação Nacional dos Magistrados da Justiça do Trabalho (Anamatra) e Associação Nacional dos Procuradores do Trabalho (ANPT) que contesta a Lei federal nº 9.005, de 1995, que autoriza o uso controlado do amianto. O primeiro posicionamento do Supremo foi no ano passado, quando os ministros mantiveram, em caráter liminar, a Lei de São Paulo nº 12.684, de 2007, que proíbe a comercialização e o uso de produtos contendo amianto.
No caso, questiona-se a competência do município para legislar sobre o tema. Lewandowski afirmou que não há fundamentos suficientes para a concessão da liminar. Para o advogado Alexandre Lindoso, do Alino & Roberto e Advogados, que defende a Associação Brasileira dos Expostos ao Amianto (Abrea) - que ingressou com pedido de amicus curiae na ação -, a negativa da liminar sinaliza uma jurisprudência que pode se consolidar na corte.

sexta-feira, 13 de março de 2009

Blog do Mendes Thame publica texto jóia!

Agora fazemos escola. Mas aprendemos a lição?
Enviado em 13 de Março de 2009 Publicado por admin
O PROER, criado pelo Fernando Henrique Cardoso, foi alvo da ira implacável dos petistas, que diziam servir apenas para salvar da bancarrota os banqueiros amigos. O governador José Serra, recentemente, também foi alvejado por paus e pedras dessa retórica furiosa, ao criar programa para remunerar melhor os professores da rede pública paulista, que apresentassem melhores resultados nas aulas proferidas e maior dedicação aos alunos. Mario Covas e FHC, implantando programas habitacionais para a baixa renda e a concessão de benefícios a famílias carentes, estabeleceram que fosse a mulher a receber o título de propriedade ou a sacar na boca do caixa a prestação pecuniária.
Hoje, é o governo Lula que se beneficia da estabilidade dos ativos financeiros dos bancos nacionais, inclusive os bancos públicos, e sua ministra do coração diz irá realizar programa habitacional no qual será a mulher ou a chefe de família a receber o título e o financiamento habitacional. Agora, o presidente Barack Obama lança programa de reforma educacional nas escolas públicas dos EEUU centrado em estímulos direcionados ao professor, visto como mola mestra de qualquer sistema de ensino e de formação das novas gerações.
Qual lição tirar desses fatos? O Brasil de 2009 tem as condições de que desfruta para melhor enfrentar a crise econômica global de hoje porque aprimorou suas instituições e a gestão financeira e de políticas públicas, desde a década de 90. Foi o que reconheceu a economista do FMI, Teresa Ter-Minassiam, em palestra proferida dia 10 de março, terça-feira última, elogiando nossa política monetária que atravessou os governos FHC e Lula, incólume. Ter-Minassiam, vice-diretora do Departamento do Hemisfério Ocidental, entre 1997 e 2000, liderou as negociações do Fundo com o Brasil, e tomava aqui periodicamente nossa lição de casa em 1999, quando atravessamos grave crise fiscal e de balanço de pagamentos.
Mas também se pode imaginar que não tivemos uma bolha do sub-prime imobiliário apenas porque nosso sistema de financiamento habitacional é restritivo, as condições de emprego e renda de nossa população, a médio-longo prazo, incertas e o crédito para habitação escasso, bastando olhar para nossas cidades, onde vivem em torno de 80% da população brasileira, e as periferias carentes cheias de barracos e puxadinhos, para ver como há espaço para gerar empregos e renda e, quem sabe, até melhorar a qualidade urbanística de cidades sufocadas por um crescimento explosivo e sem regras por décadas. Medidas recentes, acertadas no curto prazo, como a redução do IPI de veículos, não foram acompanhadas de condicionantes como a aplicação exclusiva para os movidos a álcool ou o aumento da utilização na produção automobilística assim beneficiada de componentes e peças de fabricação nacional, demonstrando o quanto de precipitação e casuísmo houve na iniciativa, que deverá ser renovada e aperfeiçoada já a partir de abril de 2009, mas o governo não dá sinais de saber aproveitar e usá-la para aprofundar ganhos ambientais e econômicos.
Temos muito que fazer e pouco tempo para errar e corrigir erros. O melhor então é deixar de jogar pra platéia e nos preocupar em somar esforços e ouvir, mais que falar, para agir refletidamente.
Mendes Thame